Top Qs
Timeline
Chat
Perspective

Vote-ratio monotonicity

Property of apportionment methods From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

Vote-ratio monotonicity
Remove ads
Remove ads

Vote-ratio,[1]:Sub.9.6 weight-ratio,[2] or population-ratio monotonicity[3]:Sec.4 is a property of some apportionment methods. It says that if the entitlement for grows at a faster rate than (i.e. grows proportionally more than ), should not lose a seat to .[1]:Sub.9.6 More formally, if the ratio of votes or populations increases, then should not lose a seat while gains a seat. An apportionment method violating this rule may encounter population paradoxes.

A particularly severe variant, where voting for a party causes it to lose seats, is called a no-show paradox. The largest remainders method exhibits both population and no-show paradoxes.[4]:Sub.9.14

Remove ads

Population-pair monotonicity

Pairwise monotonicity says that if the ratio between the entitlements of two states increases, then state should not gain seats at the expense of state . In other words, a shrinking state should not "steal" a seat from a growing state.

Some earlier apportionment rules, such as Hamilton's method, do not satisfy VRM, and thus exhibit the population paradox. For example, after the 1900 census, Virginia lost a seat to Maine, even though Virginia's population was growing more rapidly.[5]:231–232

Remove ads

Strong monotonicity

A stronger variant of population monotonicity, called strong monotonicity requires that, if a state's entitlement (share of the population) increases, then its apportionment should not decrease, regardless of what happens to any other state's entitlement. This variant is extremely strong, however: whenever there are at least 3 states, and the house size is not exactly equal to the number of states, no apportionment method is strongly monotone for a fixed house size.[6]:Thm.4.1 Strong monotonicity failures in divisor methods happen when one state's entitlement increases, causing it to "steal" a seat from another state whose entitlement is unchanged.

However, it is worth noting that the traditional form of the divisor method, which involves using a fixed divisor and allowing the house size to vary, satisfies strong monotonicity in this sense.

Remove ads

Relation to other properties

Balinski and Young proved that an apportionment method is VRM if-and-only-if it is a divisor method.[7]:Thm.4.3

Palomares, Pukelsheim and Ramirez proved that very apportionment rule that is anonymous, balanced, concordant, homogenous, and coherent is vote-ratio monotone.[citation needed]

Vote-ratio monotonicity implies that, if population moves from state to state while the populations of other states do not change, then both and must hold.[8]:Sub.9.9

See also

References

Loading content...
Loading related searches...

Wikiwand - on

Seamless Wikipedia browsing. On steroids.

Remove ads