Top Qs
Timeline
Chat
Perspective
Inada conditions
From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Remove ads
In macroeconomics, the Inada conditions are a set of mathematical assumptions about the shape and boundary behaviour of production or utility functions that ensure well-behaved properties in economic models, such as diminishing marginal returns and proper boundary behavior, which are essential for the stability and convergence of several macroeconomic models. The conditions are named after Ken-Ichi Inada, who introduced them in 1963.[1][2] These conditions are typically imposed in neoclassical growth models — such as the Solow–Swan model, the Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans model, and overlapping generations models — to ensure that marginal returns are positive but diminishing, and that the marginal product of an input becomes infinite when its quantity approaches zero and vanishes when its quantity becomes infinitely large.
![]() | This article may be too technical for most readers to understand. (August 2017) |

Economically, these properties guarantee well-behaved model dynamics: they rule out “corner solutions” such as zero capital accumulation or unbounded growth, ensure the existence of a unique and stable steady state, and promote smooth substitution between inputs. A Cobb–Douglas production function satisfies the Inada conditions, while some constant elasticity of substitution (CES) functions do not. Although stylized and not strictly realistic, the conditions are mathematically convenient and widely used in theoretical work because they simplify the analysis of long-run convergence and stability in dynamic macroeconomic models.
The Inada conditions are commonly associated with preventing pathological behaviors in production functions, such as infinite or zero capital accumulation.
Remove ads
Statement
Given a continuously differentiable function , where and , the conditions are:
- the value of the function at is 0:
- the function is concave on , i.e. the Hessian matrix needs to be negative-semidefinite.[3] Economically this implies that the marginal returns for input are positive, i.e. , but decreasing, i.e.
- the limit of the first derivative is positive infinity as approaches 0: , meaning that the effect of the first unit of input has the largest effect
- the limit of the first derivative is zero as approaches positive infinity: , meaning that the effect of one additional unit of input is 0 when approaching the use of infinite units of
Remove ads
Consequences
Summarize
Perspective
The elasticity of substitution between goods is defined for the production function as , where is the marginal rate of technical substitution. It can be shown that the Inada conditions imply that the elasticity of substitution between components is asymptotically equal to one (although the production function is not necessarily asymptotically Cobb–Douglas, a commonplace production function for which this condition holds).[4][5]
In stochastic neoclassical growth model, if the production function does not satisfy the Inada condition at zero, any feasible path converges to zero with probability one, provided that the shocks are sufficiently volatile.[6]
Remove ads
References
Further reading
Wikiwand - on
Seamless Wikipedia browsing. On steroids.
Remove ads