Top Qs
Timeline
Chat
Perspective

Sequential proportional approval voting

Multiple-winner electoral system From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

Sequential proportional approval voting
Remove ads

Sequential proportional approval voting (SPAV) or reweighted approval voting (RAV)[1] is an electoral system that extends the concept of approval voting to a multiple winner election. It is a simplified version of proportional approval voting. It is a special case of Thiele's voting rules, proposed by Danish statistician Thorvald N. Thiele in the early 1900s.[2] It was used in Sweden from 1909 to 1921, when it was replaced by a "party-list" style system, and is still used for some local elections.[3][4]

Thumb
Flow chart of SPAV calculation
Remove ads

Description

Summarize
Perspective

Sequential proportional approval voting uses approval voting ballots to elect multiple winners on a round-by-round basis. With approval voting ballots, each voter may support any number of candidates on their ballot as they see fit. For tabulation, each ballot is weighted according to a formula, the candidate with the most support is elected, and the process is repeated until there are no more seats to fill.[5][6]

The aforementioned formula is as follows: where is the number of candidates approved on that ballot who were already elected in the previous rounds, and is the final weight of the ballot. For the first round, is naturally 0, and so each ballot has a weight of 1. A SPAV election with only one seat to fill is identical to an approval voting election. Other weighting formulas may be used while still being referred to as SPAV.

Remove ads

Example

Summarize
Perspective
Thumb
Illustration of the example election. Candidates with the most votes wins for each round. When a candidate is elected they are removed for the next round.

As a clarifying example, consider an election for a committee with three winners. There are six candidates, representing two main parties: A, B, and C from one party, and X, Y, and Z from another party. About two-thirds of the voters support the first party, and the other third of the voters support the second party. Each voter casts their vote by selecting all the candidates they support. The following table shows the results of the votes. Each row represents a possible candidate support combination and the first column indicates how many ballots were cast with that combination. The bottom row shows the number of votes each candidate received.

More information # of votes, Candidate A ...

Because Candidate C has the most support, they are the first winner, , and they cannot win any subsequent rounds. For the second round, any ballot which voted for Candidate C is given a weight of one half. Below is the chart for round 2. A column has been added to indicate the weight of each set of ballots.

More information # of votes, Weight of Vote ...

Despite Candidates A and B having so many votes in the first round, Candidate X is the second winner, , because most of the ballots that support A and B also support C and thus already have representation on the council. In round 3, ballots that voted for both candidates X and C have their vote weighted by one third. Any ballot that supports only one of the two winners will be weighted by one half. Ballots that indicate support for neither remain at full weight. Below is a table representing that information.

More information # of votes, Weight of Vote ...

Candidate B is the third and final winner, . The final result has two winners from the party that had about two thirds of the votes, and one winner from the party that had about one third of the votes. If approval voting had been used instead, the final committee would have all three candidates from the first party, as they had the highest three vote totals without scaling.

Remove ads

Properties

Summarize
Perspective

SPAV satisfies the fairness property called justified representation whenever the committee size is at most 5, but might violate it when the committee size is at least 6.[7][8]

More information Pareto efficiency, Committee monotonicity ...

There is a small incentive towards tactical voting where a voter may withhold approval from candidates who are likely to be elected, just like there is with cumulative voting and the single non-transferable vote. SPAV is a much computationally simpler algorithm than harmonic proportional approval voting and other proportional methods, permitting votes to be counted either by hand, rather than requiring a computer to determine the outcome.[9]

When comparing sequential proportional approval to single transferable vote (STV), SPAV is more likely to elect candidates that individually represent the average voter, where STV is more likely to elect a range of candidates that match the distribution of the voters. The larger the number of candidates elected, the smaller the practical difference.[10]

See also

References

Loading content...
Loading related searches...

Wikiwand - on

Seamless Wikipedia browsing. On steroids.

Remove ads