Top Qs
Timeline
Chat
Perspective

Effective number of parties

Concept in political party systems From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

Effective number of parties
Remove ads
Remove ads

In political science, the effective number of parties is a diversity index introduced by Laakso and Rein Taagepera (1979),[1] which provides for an adjusted number of political parties in a country's party system, weighted by their relative size. The measure is especially useful when comparing party systems across countries.[2]

The size of a party can be measured by either:

  1. The effective number of electoral parties (ENEP) weights parties by their share of the vote.
  2. The effective number of parliamentary parties (ENPP) weights parties by their share of seats in the legislature.

The number of parties equals the effective number of parties only when all parties have equal strength. In any other case, the effective number of parties is lower than the actual number of parties. The effective number of parties is a frequent operationalization for political fragmentation. Political concentration can seen as the share of power of large political parties.[3]

Thumb
Example of how the effective number of parties shows the fragmentation of the Dutch political landscape (1981–2017)

There are several common alternatives for how to define the effective number of parties.[4] John K. Wildgen's index of "hyperfractionalization" accords special weight to small parties.[5] Juan Molinar's index gives special weight to the largest party.[6] Dunleavy and Boucek provide a useful critique of the Molinar index.[7]

Remove ads

Measures

Summarize
Perspective

Quadratic

Laakso and Taagepera (1979) were the first to define the effective number of parties using the following formula:

where n is the number of parties with at least one vote/seat and the square of each party's proportion of all votes or seats. This is also the formula for the inverse Simpson index, or the true diversity of order 2. This definition is still the most commonly-used in political science.

This measure is equivalent to the Herfindahl–Hirschman index, used in economics; the Simpson diversity index in ecology; the inverse participation ratio (IPR) in physics; and the Rényi entropy of order in information theory.[8]

Alternatives

An alternative formula was proposed by Grigorii Golosov in 2010.[9]

which is equivalent – if we only consider parties with at least one vote/seat – to

Here, n is the number of parties, the square of each party's proportion of all votes or seats, and is the square of the largest party's proportion of all votes or seats.

Remove ads

Values

The following table illustrates the difference between the values produced by the two formulas for eight hypothetical vote or seat constellations:

More information Constellation, Largest component, fractional share ...
Remove ads

Seat product model

The effective number of parties can be predicted with the seat product model[10][11] as , where M is the district magnitude and S is the assembly size.

Effective number of parties by country

Summarize
Perspective

For individual countries the values of effective number of number of parliamentary parties (ENPP) for the last available election is shown.[12] Some of the highest effective number of parties are in Brazil, Belgium, and Bosnia and Herzegovina. European Parliament has an even higher effective number of parties if national parties are considered, yet a much lower effective number of parties if political groups of the European Parliament are considered.

More information Country, Year ...
Remove ads

See also

Remove ads

References

Loading content...
Loading related searches...

Wikiwand - on

Seamless Wikipedia browsing. On steroids.

Remove ads